Usher sobre ayudas estudiantiles: claves contemporáneas
Marzo 9, 2019
March 4th, 2019 – Alex Usher
Every once in awhile, someone comes up a “new” concept in student financing and people get very excited about it. As in most other policy fields, the “newness” is a matter of perspective and debate: there’s only so many ways you can lend students money and many of the “new” ideas are just old ideas that got discarded for various reasons and resurrect either because circumstances have changed or because proponents aren’t aware of the history (or both).
The latest in a line of such ideas is “Income Share Agreements” or ISAs, which have been growing in popularity in the United States for a few years, particularly with Silicon Valley types who like to think they have re-invented or (God Forbid) disrupted literally everything. For instance, here is a rather breathless Andrew Sorkin piece on ISAs from the NYT a couple of months ago; Linda Nazareth of the McDonald-Laurier institute had a similar booster article in the Globe and Mail in February.
What are ISAs, you ask? Well, to answer this question, it’s worth taking a brief tour of the history of student lending.
When you give somebody money for a purpose – going to school, say – we tend to think of that money as coming in one of two forms: as a gift (i.e. a grant/bursary/scholarship/whatever) or as a loan. Now in regular life, loans have to be collateralized: you have to have some assets which can be used as security on a loan. But student loans work on a different principle: most students have no assets, and the education students are buying with their loans can’t be easily collateralized. So what governments do is simply assume a bunch of risk on students’ behalf and lend them the money, usually at concessionary rates with lots of assistance during repayment (yes, I know, loans with interest rates above prime don’t sound concessionary, but given that they are interest-free while in school and default rates are relatively high compared to commercial loans, they are).
Now, over the years various governments have, with the best of intentions, complicated student lending substantially, to the point where lots of well-meaning casual observers of the scene simply have no idea what governments are doing any more. For one thing, many started offering various forms of income-based assistance; suspending repayment below a certain threshold, scaling payments to income, etc. In some cases – like in New Zealand and the UK, we even have given up the normal infrastructure of loan repayment and turned administration of the whole thing over to the tax system. Combined with scaling payments to income, that starts to make student loans look a lot more like a form of income tax or “graduate tax”, even though they are clearly not because each borrower has a balance and the tax stops when the balance drops to zero.
Of course, the thing is that lending isn’t the only way to temporarily transfer money to someone. Think of this from the perspective of a company, which can either borrow money from a bank or other financial institute and repay that amount plus interest, or it can sell a portion of ownership in the company and allow the buyer to reap rewards through a future stream of dividends and/or capital gains. Though many people credit Milton Friedman’s paper The Role of Government in Education  as the work that originated the idea of student loans, he was actually advocating for the state to assume equity shares in graduates’ future income streams. For a long time, this idea went under the name of a “human capital contract (HCCs)”, though if it were collected along with taxes it could equally have been called a “graduate tax”.
The clear difference between HCCs/graduate taxes and student loans – in theory at least – is that the commitment in the latter is limited while the former is not. In a loan, you stop paying the loan when the principal is repaid; in a graduate tax, you simply pay forever, and some people end up paying a little while others end up paying a lot. A variant of the latter was tried at Yale in the early 1970s.  It didn’t go well.
One of the barriers to public acceptance of HCCs is that many people instinctively recoil from the analogy of their future labour as being something which can be divvied up into shares. Concepts like “indentured labour” seem leap to mind. From an analytic point of view, agreeing to pay someone a share of your income over a period of time is almost indistinguishable from paying them a fixed amount over a period of time, particularly if you just express the latter as a fraction of income. And if your government has already transformed your loan into something repayable as a fraction of income (i.e. an income contingent loan) and has started collecting the loan through the income tax system, then both become difficult to distinguish from graduate taxes.
(The UK has complicated this even further by adopting a loan system which saddles all its students with high balances and relatively low repayment obligations, meaning the loans will, in a majority of cases, never be paid off before they get forgiven 35 years after graduation. Thus, graduates with high salaries will experience it as a loan which goes to a zero balance while graduates with lower salaries will just experience it as a tax on income for 35 years, and by design the student can never know which it will be until a couple of decades into repayment. Bizarre.)
Now that all that is as clear as mud, we can get back to ISAs. Despite the insistence by various Silicon Valley types that they’ve found something new, ISAs are pretty much just Friedman’s HCCs, privately administered, and modified for reasons of public acceptability to look more like loans and less like a graduate tax. Nothing more, nothing less.
The real question is: given all the various forms of public loans which are available, and the increasing degree to which they have been made income-contingent, what is the actual market for ISAs? When does it make sense to use them and when does it not? More on this tomorrow.

 

 
March 5th, 2019 – Alex Usher
Yesterday, I described Income Share Agreements (ISAs) as basically a version of Milton Friedman-like Human Capital Contracts, which are very much like privately administered graduate taxes. The question we will answer today is: under what circumstances would a private ISA be preferable to a public student loan?
Assuming both were equally available and equally subsidized, then in theory a student would be indifferent between the two. But there are a few reasons why this is unlikely to be the case; and understanding these is key to understanding when and where ISAs make sense.
First, public loan systems are, for the most part, subsidized. In the Canadian system, the governments cover all interest while a student is in school (or longer – see the BC example from last month), subsidizes loan repayments for low-income graduates through the Repayment Assistance Plan (RAP) and covers losses from loan defaults. The federal government covers this partly through charging students higher interest during repayment, but there is still a residual which requires a government subsidy to cover. Unless ISAs are similarly subsidized (which they could be, if they are philanthropically funded), they will be less attractive to student loans.
Second, the unknown nature of the ultimate payment under an ISA creates some adverse selection effects. If you think you are going to make a lot of money after graduation, you would prefer a student loan, which limits your liability, over an ISA under which you may repay many times the amount you initially borrow (this ISA, at Purdue University, caps total payment at 2.5 the initial investment, which is still a heck of a lot). This means students from programs that lead to high-paying jobs (medicine, dentistry, MBAs, etc.) will probably not be inclined to use it. On the other hand, if you think you may not earn very much, you may find it more advantageous to be in an ISA than taking a loan.
This, as you might imagine, creates a huge whack of moral hazard: your plan will be overwhelmed with students with low income-prospects. To prevent this, what happens is that ISA providers simply change up the terms of their agreements to make sure that they break even no matter who shows up in the program. If they have a lot of low-future-income students, they will just lower the income thresholds and increase the repayment percentage to compensate. This is why some experts = like these folks at the Roosevelt Institute – see almost no difference between Income Share Agreements and student debt from the student point of view.
I argue that there are perhaps two good arguments in favour of ISAs. The first is that they can supplement existing student loans. Governments don’t provide unlimited amounts of money to students and frequently the maximum (currently a little under $12,000 for most students in most parts of Canada) doesn’t cover both tuition and living expenses. So, a loan might beat an ISA, but an ISA is better than nothing. That said, it’s not entirely clear why in such circumstances a lender would prefer to offer an ISA over a loan. Why not just offer another loan? It’s not like the collection costs associated with an ISA are any lower than those for a conventional loan.
The second argument is that ISAs are best for students who are debt-averse might not be equity averse. Pure debt-aversion is, I think, over-rated as a financial impediment to access, but it certainly has been proven to exist, though not in the way most people argue it does (key point: it does not appear to be linked to income background). Arguably, ISAs are a niche instrument to offer the debt-averse equity-based assistance instead of debt-based assistance. I am a bit skeptical that this would work – and there is no empirical evidence that would prove this one way or another – but I suppose it couldn’t hurt to try.
Here’s the bottom line: if, at the end of the day, the lender/investor has to cover their cost of capital, then the difference between debt instruments and equity instruments from the borrower’s perspective is pretty small. Conceivably, private ISAs have a role as a supplement to conventional loans or as a niche alternative to students who refuse to take on debt for whatever reason (ISAs could, for instance, easily be made sharia-compliant). But for the most part, increased lending with better targeted debt relief is a better alternative.

0 Comments

Submit a Comment

Tu dirección de correo electrónico no será publicada. Los campos requeridos están marcados *

PUBLICACIONES

Libros

Capítulos de libros

Artículos académicos

Columnas de opinión

Comentarios críticos

Entrevistas

Presentaciones y cursos

Actividades

Documentos de interés

Google académico

DESTACADOS DE PORTADA

Artículos relacionados

Trump y la ciencia

Trump’s anti-science appointees ‘drive demonisation of scholars’ With vaccine sceptics taking top White House posts, there are concerns that attacks on scientists who counter misinformation may become more extreme Jack Grove,November 18, 2024 Researchers who have...

Share This